Skip to main content
opinion
Open this photo in gallery:

Tiff Macklem, Governor of the Bank of Canada, holds a press conference at the Bank of Canada in Ottawa on Jan. 25, 2023.Sean Kilpatrick/The Canadian Press

Lawrence Schembri is a former deputy governor of the Bank of Canada. Steven Globerman is a professor emeritus at Western Washington University. They are senior fellows at the Fraser Institute.

With the recent decline in the inflation rate, the Bank of Canada has paused its interest rate increases and will wait to see if inflation continues to decrease toward the central bank’s 2-per-cent target. Yet at the same time, according to a growing chorus of economists and business leaders, a rigid adherence to the 2-per-cent target will depress economic activity and employment in the face of upward pressure on some prices driven by such forces as climate change and population aging.

For example, former International Monetary Fund chief economist Olivier Blanchard, in a recent editorial in Britain’s Financial Times, argued that major central banks should raise their target rates of inflation to 3 per cent from 2 per cent. His rationale is that a higher target inflation rate would increase nominal interest rates. This, in turn, would give central banks more room to lower their policy rates to stimulate economic activity in the event of an economic downturn, without hitting the zero interest rate lower bound.

Once this lower bound is reached, central banks must rely on other monetary policy tools such as quantitative easing or a negative policy rate, as was adopted by the European Central Bank. Given the uncertainty about the effectiveness and the unintended negative consequences of quantitative easing or negative policy rates, Mr. Blanchard and others favour the more traditional response of reducing the policy rate to a lower but positive level.

But if 3-per-cent inflation is preferable to 2-per-cent inflation as Mr. Blanchard suggests, why not 4-per-cent or even 5-per-cent inflation? There’s a reason that central banks have stuck so rigidly to 2 per cent for so long. To abandon that target now would be misguided.

Mr. Blanchard argues that inflation expectations remain well anchored as long as the inflation rate does not much exceed 3 per cent. But that’s a debatable conjecture. Evidence indicates that higher prevailing inflation leads to more volatile inflation, implying that inflation expectations could become less anchored. This, in turn, would distort price and wage setting, misallocate resources and render monetary policy less effective. Central banks have committed to a 2-per-cent inflation target for decades, and inflation in Canada and other advanced economies prior to the pandemic was low, stable and predictable, thereby contributing to a better functioning economy.

If a central bank were to raise its target rate, it would run the risk of undermining public confidence in the central bank’s commitment to maintaining the new inflation target. Consequently, businesses and households would likely expect inflation to exceed the target rather than fall below it, thus making attaining the new target more difficult.

However, even if central banks were able to reanchor inflation expectations at the new target, higher and more volatile inflation would inflict other adverse effects. In particular, higher inflation is effectively a regressive tax. Reductions in purchasing power tend to be concentrated among lower-income workers less able to recoup such losses with wage gains, and also less able to own assets that increase in value with inflation, particularly housing.

Also, since the tax systems in Canada and other advanced economies are not fully indexed to inflation, taxpayers will bear a higher tax burden as nominal incomes and asset prices increase, even if the inflation-adjusted incomes and asset values do not change. This tax rate drift will distort the incentives to work, save and invest, and thereby reduce productivity and economic growth.

Finally, some advocates for a higher inflation target rate believe that moving the current rate of inflation back down to the 2-per-cent target will result in an unacceptably high and persistent rate of unemployment. However, both theory and the evidence from labour markets over the past three decades suggest there’s no long-run relationship between inflation and unemployment. Inflation is ultimately a monetary phenomenon that can be controlled by the central bank.

In the absence of any compelling benefit to increasing the target inflation rate, and given the economic risks and costs of doing so, the Bank of Canada and other central banks should stay firm and maintain their 2-per-cent inflation target.

Follow related authors and topics

Authors and topics you follow will be added to your personal news feed in Following.

Interact with The Globe